International Journal of Research and Innovation in Social Science

Submission Deadline- 14th February 2025
February Issue of 2025 : Publication Fee: 30$ USD Submit Now
Submission Deadline-05th March 2025
Special Issue on Economics, Management, Sociology, Communication, Psychology: Publication Fee: 30$ USD Submit Now
Submission Deadline-20th February 2025
Special Issue on Education, Public Health: Publication Fee: 30$ USD Submit Now

Effect of Market Entry on Generic Drug Prices: Medicare Data 2007-2022

  • Nguyen Xuan Nguyen
  • Steven Sheingold
  • Arielle Bosworth
  • Rachael Zuckerman
  • Thomas Buchmueller
  • 1485-1496
  • Feb 6, 2025
  • Healthcare Management

Effect of Market Entry on Generic Drug Prices: Medicare Data 2007-2022

*Nguyen Xuan Nguyen, Ph.D., Steven Sheingold, Ph.D., Arielle Bosworth, Rachael Zuckerman, Ph.D., Thomas Buchmueller, Ph.D

Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services

DOI: https://dx.doi.org/10.47772/IJRISS.2025.9010123

Received: 01 January 2025; Accepted: 06 January 2025; Published: 06 February 2025

ABSTRACT

Using the Medicare Part D drug event (PDE) data from 2007 to 2022, and both fixed effects or random effects at the drug level, we estimate the relationship of competitors and prices within each drug level while controlling for factors across drugs for 3 periods, 2007-11, 2012-15, and 2016-2019. We follow a drug 24 months and 36 months after first generic entry to examine whether the relationship between number of competitors and price would change over time.

We find that in recent years new generic markets continue to be competitive. Drug prices fall with increasing number of generic competitors. Prices decline by 20% in markets with about 3 competitors. Prices continue to decline by 70% to 80% relative to the pre-generic entry price in markets of 10 or more competitors following 3 years after first generic entry. We also find that the impact of competition on relative prices are similar for generic drugs first entering the market in the most recent period 2016-2019 to the earlier periods, 2007-11 or 2012-15.

INTRODUCTION

The U.S. has a number of policies related to drug pricing, affordability, and availability.  To encourage manufacturers to innovate with new therapies, patent policy rewards the creation of new branded medicines.  As those patents come to an end, generic drug manufacturers may enter a market and seek to sell their products at lower prices than the competing brand drugs.  Policies that support competition of lower price generics for brand drugs, once the generics become available for sale, helps to make drug prices more affordable for taxpayers, payers, and patients.

Generic competition intensified in the 2010s with the expiration of market exclusivity of a large number of branded drugs in 2011 and 2012, followed by similarly large numbers of generic-drug approvals in 2016 and 2017 [6]. In 2017, the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) also updated its policy to prioritize the review of generic applications up to the third generic approval of a drug as a means to further encourage drug competition.[1] In that year, the FDA approved 1,027 Abbreviated New Drug Applications (ANDAs), with 843 fully approved applications and 184 tentatively approved applications. 2017 broke the previous record set in 2016 of 813 ANDAs: 630 full approvals and 183 tentative approvals.[2] The 2017 approvals included 80 “first generic” drugs, which are the first generic alternatives to a brand-name product. This growth in generic drug approvals has continued in recent years with more than 956 approved or tentatively approved generic drug applications in 2023 [17,18].

These new generic drugs are expected to further moderate the rate of growth in drug spending [39]. In 2022, it was estimated that 91% of all prescriptions in the United States were filled as generic drugs [17, 18]. The literature demonstrates that increased competition – measured by number of suppliers – in new generic markets has a substantial impact in reducing prices relative to the brand drug[3] [15, 29].

At the same time, however, there have been concerns that mergers and acquisitions in generic manufacturing could impact the potential savings of increased generic use [21].  Between 2014 and 2016, there were nearly 100 mergers worth close to $80 billion [23]. This raises the question whether new generic markets will get the same competitive response as in the past, as well as whether low profit margins will result in an increasing number of noncompetitive generic markets and price spikes [28]. During 2012-15, there were price increases, some very large, for many generic drugs that are the standard of care for certain diseases [49]. In addition, many of the ANDAs approved by FDA in recent years have been for subsequent generics – that is generic versions for markets that already have at least three competitors, raising concerns that such approvals do not have the same price reducing effect as approval for the first three competitors in the market [32].

This study evaluates these concerns by updating a previous ASPE Issue Brief that compared the effects of generic competition on prices of the earlier periods of 2007-2011 and 2012-2015[4] with adding the most recent period of 2016-2019. The study examines whether or not the expected effect of generic entry on prices is similar to the prior two periods.

PRIOR LITERATURE

The literature consistently shows that the number of generic market competitors are associated with lower generic drug prices.[5] The studies and range of price reductions are summarized in Table 1. These studies found that prices declined by about 15% to 40% in markets with 3 to 5 competitors and by 60% to 90% in markets of 10 or more competitors.

Table 1. Summary of Estimated Generic Drug Price Reduction Associate with the Number of Competitors

Table 1. Summary of Estimated Generic Drug Price Reduction Associate with the Number of Competitors

Two key differences among these studies include the specification of competition and the use of different data sources and time periods.

First, the specification of competition can be categorized into two approaches: (1) using a discrete number of competitors (N) or some variant of N,[6] or (2) using a set of binary variables to describe the number of competitors. The first approach, by using the number of firms as an explanatory variable, assumes that the effect of an increase by 1 in the number of firms is independent of the initial number of firms and that the relationship between the number of suppliers and price is predetermined in the equation. For example, generic price is assumed to vary linearly with N, the number of firms [22, 10, 15]; with N and N2 [9]; or with N and 1/N [51]. The second approach for measuring competition uses a set of binary variables to represent the number of competitors.[7]  Unlike using a single number as a dependent variable, this specification would not assume a priori functional form on the effect of additional competitors on price but would allow the marginal effect of an additional firm to vary with the number of firms [33]. Lower estimates of price reduction are associated with the flexible specification using a set of binary variables to represent the number of competitors.

Second, many studies predate Medicare Part D and as such use IMS national sales data or private payers claims data. In contrast, our study uses the latest Medicare Part D drug events data (PDE) data from 2007 through 2022 to examine all generics entering the Part D markets during 2007-2019 and follow these drugs for 24 and 36 months after entry.

DATA AND METHODS

Data

To examine the relationship between number of suppliers and price, we use the latest Medicare Part D (PDE) data from 2007 to 2022, hence, complementing most work in the literature that relies on the IMS national sales data or private payers’ claims data.[8] We restrict the data to only drugs that had generic entry from 2007 through 2019 to allow us to follow a drug that entered in 2019 for 36 months. We follow each drug for exactly 36 months after generic entry.  We also exclude biosimilars[9] and orphan drugs, as well as molecule-form-months where the drug/drug-class becomes available over the counter. Finally, we restrict to single-ingredient drugs with at least 24 months of generic competition following entry. For the purposes of this study, a drug is defined by a combination of molecule (active ingredient), route of administration, and dosage form.[10],[11] We consider an entry to occur in the first month in which a drug has positive sales following at least a quarter of zero sales.

We compute average prices of each drug by averaging ingredient costs across the NDC-level to the drug-level, separately for brand and generic.[12]  We also compute average prices in two ways: (1) the arithmetic average of median prices and (2) quantity-weighted average prices; both methods yield similar results. To allow for cross-year comparison, all prices are inflation-adjusted to January 2016 prices using the Consumer Price Index.[13]

Methods

Our unit of analysis is a drug month (molecule-form-month). We assessed both a random effects and molecule-form level fixed effects multivariate regression models at the drug level to focus on the relationship of competitors and prices within each drug while controlling for factors across drugs.[14]

We use multivariate regressions to compare the monthly price trajectory following the first generic entry[15] to the baseline price (the average brand price of the drug during 6 months prior to the first generic entry).[16]  This ratio, described below, is our main dependent variable.

We use the model:

Where:

i denotes the molecule, f denotes the form, and c denotes the therapeutic class the molecule is in.

t denotes the number of months since the beginning of 2007 starting with January 2007 having t=1.

u=u(if) is the month before generic competition for drug i in form f.

𝑃𝑖𝑓𝑢 is the price of the branded drug with molecule i and form f during the baseline period. Price is the quantity weighted average price computed as the total Part D ingredient cost divided by the total quantity dispensed.

𝑝𝑖𝑓𝑡 is the price of generics of molecule i in form f and month t. This represents the average price of generics across all generic manufacturers.

𝑛𝑖𝑓𝑡 is the number of generic labelers of molecule i in form f in month t.

𝑁𝑐𝑡 is the number of molecules in therapeutic class c in month t.

𝑉𝑖𝑢 is the average number of beneficiaries taking the drug in the baseline period.

𝐺𝑐𝑢 is the geometric average of 𝑟𝑐𝑡 over the baseline period:

  • 𝑟𝑐𝑡=𝑆𝑐𝑡/𝑆𝑐,𝑡−1, i.e., 𝑟𝑐𝑡 is the growth in the number of beneficiaries taking a drug from class c in month t relative to month t-1
  • 𝑆𝑐𝑡 is the total number of beneficiaries taking a drug from class c in month

𝜙𝑖𝑓 is a fixed effect for the molecule-form. This captures all the variables that aren’t time varying such as drug form, class, year of patent expiration, pre-patent expiry market size, marginal cost as a fraction of price, etc.

Competition, the main independent variable 𝑛𝑖𝑓𝑡, is based on the number of labelers (manufacturers or marketers) of the drug. [17] We also examined the number of companies manufacturing a drug as an alternative independent variable, and found similar results.[18]  For this sensitivity analysis, manufacturers of authorized generics were considered generic manufacturers even if they are the same as the brand manufacturer.

Rather than using the concentration ratio or the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, a commonly accepted measure of market concentration, we measure the number of labelers as this is the policy lever the FDA exercises to affect competition when it approves an ANDA. We describe the number of competitors, [19] using a series of binary variables to capture the number of generic manufacturers/labelers and truncating those with more than 10, adapted from Reiffen and Ward in 2005. This specification allows us to estimate a non-linear relationship between number of entries and price reductions. As the excluded category is one labeler,  is represented by 9 binary variables, where 1(𝑛𝑖𝑓𝑡=10) represents (𝑛𝑖𝑓𝑡≥10) and where the control is =1.

The regression controls for the size of the market, with fixed effects for the molecule-form. We take the number of beneficiaries taking the drug during the baseline period (6 months prior to the first generic entry) and apply the associated growth rate for the drug class to project what the current market size would have been in the absence of changes. Thus, the term is a proxy for the current size of the market that should be unaffected by the current prices. We also assume exponential growth after generic entry; the (t-u) term is a power so, for instance, 3 months after generic entry we cube the growth rate.

The regressions are also clustered at the drug-group level (such as antidepressants) in order to adjust for potential correlation among drugs within the same drug-group.[20]

The interpretation of a is the relative generic price when there is 1 generic competitor to the branded drug. The other are the reductions in the relative price from a when there are k labelers.

We use the model results to predict relative prices for each corresponding number of labelers, holding all regressors at their mean and setting the fixed effects to zero. These marginal effects are presented in the results below.

Some previous work pointed out that competition was intense for a period after a brand’s loss-of-exclusivity (LOE), but then could wane over time [14]. This study follows a drug 24 months as well as 36 months after first generic entry in order to see whether the relationship between number of labelers and price would change over time.  We also test the hypothesis that drugs with more recent LOE might face less competition than those earlier by estimating separately the competition-price relationship for drugs with first generic entry during 2007-2011, 2012-2015, and the latest period of 2016-2019.[21]

RESULTS

Descriptive statistics

Table 2 presents descriptive statistics on the number of drugs with first generic entry during the 3 periods, 2007-2011, 2012-2015, and 2016-2019, their associated number of labelers, and average brand and generic prices.

The level of competition, measured by the average number of labelers per drug, remains relatively stable over the 3 periods: 5.15 average labelers per drug in 2007-2011, 4.42 average labelers per drug in 2012-2015, and 5.13 average labelers per drug in 2016-2019 (Table 2).

Table 2. Generic Drug Characteristics by Market Size, 3 Years after First Entry

First Generic Entry During 2007-11 by Market Size (by Average Number of Beneficiaries)
Characteristics Small (<5,00 users Medium (000 – per   To
Time Period 2007 201 201 2007 2012 2016 2007 2012 2016 2007 2012 20-
Number of Drugs 77 88 100 29 23 18 40 42 29 146 153 147
Average Number of Labelers 3.10 2.75 3.51 4.03 5.09 7.67 9.90 7.55 9.14 5.15 4.42 5.13
Mean Brand Price $44 $59 $141 $11 $15 $140 $13 $26 $17 $28 $42 $115
Mean Generic Price $34 $45 $93 $8 $8 $55 $7 $14 $10 $22 $31 $71
Generic Price as Percent of Brand Price 77% 76% 66% 71% 55% 39% 56% 55% 61% 76% 73% 62%

We grouped markets into three categories based on the number of treated Medicare Part D patients at time of initial generic entry: small (less than 5,000 users per month), medium (5,000 to 14,999 users per month), and large (15,000 or more users per month). Sixty percent of the drugs in our study are in small markets (265/446). The small markets are concentrated with an average of about 3 labelers per drug. As expected, competition in the large markets is more intense, averaging close to 10 labelers per drug.

Figure 2 shows the average number of labelers from Table 2 graphically. We find that the larger the size of the markets -measured by the number of users per month- the greater the number of entrants and, therefore, competitors. In addition, Figure 3 shows that a large number of drugs have 1 to 3 competitors in the 3 years after first entry.

Figure 2. Generic Drug Characteristics by Market Size, 3 Years after First Entry, 2016-19

Figure 3. Generic Drugs by Maximum Number of Labelers, 3 Years after First Entry

Number of Labelers and Relative Prices after First Generic Entry

Table 3 shows the regression results for all 3 time periods: 2007-2011, 2012-2015, and 2016-2019. We find that prices continue to decrease as the number of labelers increases up to 10 or more labelers. Following 3 years after first generic entry, relative prices are about 55 to 65 percentage points lower in markets with 10 or more labelers relative to markets with only 1 generic labeler. This implies that, for example, if the generic-to-brand price ratio is about 75% to 85% when there is 1 generic labeler, then the price ratio could be as low as 20% in markets of 10 or more labelers.

Table 3. Impact of Competition (Binaries for Number of Labelers) on Generic Relative Price

Entry during 2007-11 Entry during 2012-15 Entry during 2016-19
Number of Labelers 1
2 -0.011 -0.047 0.026 -0.064 -0.094 -0.033 -0.025 -0.072 0.022
3 -0.061 -0.117 -0.005 -0.093 -0.131 -0.055 -0.126 -0.176 -0.076
4 -0.089 -0.160 -0.018 -0.150 -0.191 -0.109 -0.184 -0.234 -0.135
5 -0.183 -0.272 -0.093 -0.227 -0.279 -0.176 -0.259 -0.324 -0.194
6 -0.224 -0.313 -0.136 -0.312 -0.380 -0.244 -0.314 -0.376 -0.252
7 -0.297 -0.400 -0.194 -0.339 -0.494 -0.184 -0.351 -0.413 -0.288
8 -0.406 -0.511 -0.301 -0.504 -0.599 -0.410 -0.388 -0.452 -0.324
9 -0.479 -0.577 -0.382 -0.537 -0.623 -0.451 -0.436 -0.500 -0.372
10+ -0.656 -0.757 -0.554 -0.662 -0.750 -0.574 -0.544 -0.616 -0.473
Number of molecules in the same drug group -0.005 -0.010 0.000 -0.002 -0.003 0.000 0.004 0.000 0.007
Proxy for predicted number of patients in the absence of the drug going off patent Number of Beneficiaries (in millions) -0.781 -3.205 1.643 -1.126 -2.093 -0.158 -0.041 -0.047 -0.036

Source: Analysis of Medicare Part D claims, 2007-2022.

Regression with molecule-form fixed effects, clustering at the drug group (GPI2) level, for all drugs with generic entry between 2007-11, 2012-15, and 2016-19. N=1 supplier is the control group. Other controls include measures of market size and substitutability of the drugs within the therapeutic drug group.

The generic relative price, the dependent variable, is the price of the generic drug relative to that of the brand drug 6 months prior to generic entry.

Although the magnitude of the estimated impacts beyond about 7 labelers tends to be lower for the latest period (suggesting that the effect of entry beyond 7 labelers has diminished somewhat relative to earlier periods), these differences are not statistically significant.

Comparing this to the number of labelers per drug shown in Figure 3, there is potential for additional savings if more drugs were to have more labelers, rather than the current state where a large number of drugs have three or fewer labelers.

The results also show that the larger the market size, proxied by the predicted number of patients in the absence of the drug going off patent, , the greater the price reduction.  The price effects of market size is significant across the 3 time periods. We also find that the higher the substitutability among drugs within a therapeutic class (measured 𝑁𝑐𝑡, the number of molecules in therapeutic class c), the greater the price reduction for drugs whose first generic entry occurred in the periods of 2007-11 and 2012-15. The magnitude of the price impact of this variable, however, is small.

Graphical Results: Number of Labelers and Relative Prices following 3 Years after First Generic Entry During 2016-2019 compared to 2007-2011 and 2012-2015

The regression results in Table 3 are displayed graphically for the 3 periods in Figure 4. Figure 4 compares the relationship between the number of labelers and relative prices of generics 3 years after entry during the 3 periods: 2007-2011, 2012-2015, and 2016-2019. The plots show that prices continue to decline with increasing competition.

Based on data that follow each generic drug for 3 years after first entry during the latest period 2016-2019, the expected price ratio in markets with 10 or more labelers, the expected price ratio is close to 30%, implying a 70% decline in prices relative to the pre-generic entry price.[22] As suggested by the 95-percent confidence intervals in Table 3 (and the t-tests of the differences) the differences in the slopes of the 3 price lines in Figure 4 are not significant at the 5 percent level.

Figure 4:

In the earlier periods of 2012-2015 and 2007-2011, the pattern of higher competition leading to lower relative prices seems to be stronger as the expected price ratio is about close to 20%, implying an 80% decline in prices relative to the pre-generic entry price. Moreover, as shown in Table 3, the differences of the marginal price impacts among the 3 time periods are not statistically significant.[23]

CONCLUSION

This study finds that generic competition is consistently associated with lower drug prices, and our estimated impacts are within the ranges found in the literature (see Table 1). We find that prices decline by about 20% in markets with about 3 competitors. Prices decline further with more competitors; we find that prices decline by 70% to 80% after 2 to 3 years of first generic entry in markets that reach 10 or more competitors. This study supports prior findings that prices continue to decline with increasing entrants.[24]

In conclusion, the results provide clear evidence to support policies that promote generic entry. In addition to promoting generic entry, policy efforts to maintain effective supplier competition are important for containing drug prices in the longer run.

REFERENCES

  1. Aitken, M., E.R. Berndt, D.M. Cutler, M. Kleinrock and L. Maini. Has the Era of Slow Growth for Prescription Drug Spending Ended? Health Affairs. 2016; 35(9):1595-1603.
  2. Berndt, Ernst R., Richard Mortimer, Ashoke Bhattacharjya, Andrew Parece, and Edward Tuttle. Authorized Generic Drugs, Price Competition, And Consumers’ Welfare. Health Affairs. 2007; 26, no. 3: 790–799; 10.1377/hlthaff.26.3.790. Available at: https://www.healthaffairs.org/doi/pdf/10.1377/hlthaff.26.3.790
  3. Berndt, Ernst R. and Newhouse, Joseph, P. Pricing and reimbursement in US pharmaceutical markets. National Bureau of Economic Research. August 2010; Working Paper 16297 (draft of handbook chapter). Available at: https://www.nber.org/papers/w16297.pdf
  4. Berndt, Ernst R., and Murray L. Aitken. Brand Loyalty, Generic Entry and Price Competition in Pharmaceuticals in the Quarter Century after the 1984 Waxman-Hatch Legislation. National Bureau of Economic Research. October 2010; Working Paper 16431. Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w16431
  5. Berndt, E., and M. Aitken. Brand Loyalty, Generic Entry and Price Competition in Pharmaceuticals in the Quarter Century after the 1984 Waxman-Hatch Legislation. International Journal of the Economics of Business. 2011; 18, no. 2: 177–201.
  6. Berndt, Ernst R.; Conti, Rena M.; Murphy, Stephen J. The Landscape of Us Generic Prescription Drug Markets, 2004-2016. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2017; Working Paper 2364. Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w23640
  7. Berndt, Ernst R.; Conti, Rena M.; Murphy, Stephen J. The Generic Drug User Fee Amendments: An Economic Perspective. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2017; Working Paper No. 23642.
  8. Bond, R., and D. Lean. Sales, Promotion and Product Differentiation in Two Prescription Markets. Washington, DC: Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commission. 1977.
  9. Caves, R., M. Whinston, and M. Hurwicz. Patent Expiration, Entry, and Competition in the U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics. 1991; 1–66. Available at: https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/1991/01/1991_bpeamicro_caves.pdf
  10. Chintan Dave, Abraham Hartzema, and Aaron Kesselheim. Prices of Generic Drugs Associated with Numbers of Manufacturers. N Engl J Med. 2017; 377:2597-2598. DOI: 10.1056/NEJMc1711899. Available at: https://www.nejm.org/doi/10.1056/NEJMc1711899
  11. CMS Factsheet: Medicare Drug Price Negotiation Program (cms.gov) (https://www.cms.gov/ files/document/fact-sheet-medicare-selected-drug-negotiation-list-ipay-2026.pdf)
  12. Conrad, Ryan, Luther R. Generic Competition and Drug Prices: New Evidence Linking Greater Generic Competition and Lower Generic Drug Prices. FDA, Center for Drug Evaluation and Research Report. 2019. Available at: https://www.fda.gov/media/133509/download
  13. Cook, A. How Increased Competition from Generic Drugs Has Affected Prices and Returns in the Pharmaceutical Industry. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office Study. 1998.
  14. Conti, Rena M.; Berndt, Ernst R. Four Facts Concerning Competition in U.S. Generic Prescription Drug Markets. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2019; Working Paper 26194. Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w26194
  15. Food and Drug Administration. New Evidence Linking Greater Generic Competition and Lower Generic Drug Prices. FDA. 2019. Available at: https://www.fda.gov/about-fda/center-drug-evaluation-and-research-cder/generic-competition-and-drug-prices
  16. https://www.fda.gov/about-fda/center-drug-evaluation-and-research-cder/fda-listing-authorized-generics
  17. https://www.fda.gov/drugs/generic-drugs/office-generic-drugs-2022-annual-report
  18. https://www.fda.gov/drugs/generic-drugs/office-generic-drugs-2023-annual-report
  19. https://www.fda.gov/about-fda/center-drug-evaluation-and-research-cder/generic-competition-and-drug-prices
  20. https://www.fda.gov/media/133509/download
  21. https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/Future%20of%20Pharma%20Workshop%20–%20 Summary.pdf
  22. Frank, R., and D. Salkever, (1995). Generic Entry and the Pricing of Pharmaceuticals. National Bureau of Economic Research. 1995; Working Paper No. 5306 (Also Reprint No. r2121) Issued in October 1995. Available at: https://www.nber.org/papers/w5306.pdf
  23. Gagnon, Marc-André and Karena D. Volesky. Merger mania: mergers and acquisitions in the generic drug sector from 1995 to 2016. Globalization and Health. 2017; 13:62. Available at: https://globalizationandhealth.biomedcentral.com/articles/10.1186/s12992-017-0285-x
  24. Hernandez I, et al. (2023). Reimbursement to Pharmacies for Generic Drugs by Medicare Part D Sponsors. Jama, December 5, 2023. doi:10.1001/jama.2023.21481
  25. IMS Institute for Healthcare Informatics. Medicine use and Spending in the U.S.: A Review of 2015 and Outlook to 2020. April 2016.
  26. IQVIA Institute for Human Data Science. Medicine Use and Spending in the U.S., 2017-2022. 2018. Available at https://www.iqvia.com/institute/reports/medicine-use-and-spending-in-the-us-review-of-2017-outlook-to-2022
  27. IQVIA Institute for Human Data Science. Medicine Use and Spending in the U.S., 2018-2023. 2019. Available at https://www.iqvia.com/-/media/iqvia/pdfs/institute-reports/medicine-use-and-spending-in-the-us—a-review-of-2018-outlook-to-2023.pdf?_=1593533824980
  28. Mozzocchi, Andrea and Ashwin Admala Reddy. Will more generic drug approvals push prices down, or push manufacturers away? Health Forward Blog. Deloitte, January 23, 2020. Available at: https://www2.deloitte.com/us/en/blog/health-care-blog/2020/will-more-generic-drug-approvals-push-prices-down.html
  29. Nguyen Xuan Nguyen, Steven H Sheingold, Wafa Tarazi, Arielle Bosworth (2022 March). Effect of Competition on Generic Drug Prices. Appl Health Econ Health Policy. 2022 Mar; 20(2):243-253. doi: 10.1007/s40258-021-00705-w. Available at https://pubmed.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/34904207/
  30. Olson Luke and Brett Wendling. The Effect of Generic Drug Competition on Generic Drug Prices during the Hatch-Waxman 180-Day Exclusivity Period. Federal Trade Commission. 2013; Working Paper 317. Available at: https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/reports/estimating-effect-entry-generic-drug-prices-using-hatch-waxman-exclusivity/wp317.pdf
  31. Papke, L. E. and Wooldridge. Panel data methods for fractional response variables with an application to test pass rates. Journal of Econometrics. 2008; 145, pp. 121-133.
  32. Pew Charitable Trusts. FDA Approves More Generic Drugs, but Competition Still Lags: FY 2012-17 program achieves mixed results. February 2019. Available at: https://www.pewtrusts.org/-/media/assets/2019/02/fda approves more generic drugs but competition still lags.pdf
  33. Reiffen, David and Ward, Michael R. Generic Drug Industry Dynamics. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2005; 87(1): 37-49.
  34. Serra-Byrriel, M., et al. (2024 August). Drug Prices after Patent Expirations in High-Income Countries and Implications for Cost-Effectiveness Analyses. JAMA Health Forum. 2024; 5(8):e242530. doi:10.1001/jamahealthforum.2024.2530. Available at https://jamanetwork.com/journals/jama-health-forum/fullarticle/2822169
  35. Scott Morton, Fiona M. Entry decisions in the generic pharmaceutical industry. RAND Journal of Economics. 1999; 30 (3), pp. 421-440.
  36. Scott Morton, Fiona M. Barriers to Entry, Brand Advertising, and Generic Entry in the U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry. International Journal of Industrial Organization. 2000; 18: 1085–1104.
  37. Scott Morton, Fiona and Boller, Lysle T. Enabling Competition in Pharmaceutical Markets. Hutchins Center. 2017; working paper #30.
  38. Sheingold, Steven and Nguyen, Nguyen X. Impacts of Generic Competition and Benefit Management Practices on Spending for Prescription Drugs: Evidence from Medicare’s Part D Benefit. Medicare and Medicaid Research Review. 2014; 4(1). Available at: https://www.cms.gov/mmrr/Downloads/MMRR2014 004 01 a01.pdf
  39. US Department of Health and Human Services, Food and Drug Administration. How Generic Competition Advances Public Health by Improving Access to Affordable Medication. 2024.. Available at https://www.fda.gov/about-fda/center-drug-evaluation-and-research-cder/generic-competition-and-drug-prices
  40. US Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). Medicare Part B Drugs: Pricing and Incentives. 2016; ASPE Issue Brief. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/system/files/pdf/187581/PartBDrug.pdf
  41. US Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). Savings Available Under Full Generic Substitution of Multiple Source Brand Drugs in Medicare Part D. 2018; ASPE Data Point. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/system/files/pdf/259326/DP-Multisource-Brands-in-Part-D.pdf
  42. US Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). Report to Congress: Prescription Drug Pricing Report. 2019. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/system/files/pdf/262746/DrugPricingRTC2019.pdf
  43. US Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). Report to Congress: Prescription Drug Pricing. 2020. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/system/files/aspe-files/263451/2020-drug-pricing-report-congress-final.pdf
  44. US Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). Medicare FFS Part B and International Drug Prices: A Comparison of the Top 50 Drugs. 2020; ASPE Issue Brief. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/system/files/pdf/264421/Part-B%20Drugs-International-Issue-Brief.pdf
  45. https://aspe.hhs.gov/reports/international-prescription-drug-price-comparisons
  46. US Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). Competition and Prices in Generic Drug Markets 20072018. ASPE Issue Brief No. HP-2021-01. January 19, 2021. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/reports/medicare-part-d-competition-generic-drug-prices-2007-2018
  47. US Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). Generic Drug Utilization and Spending Among Medicare Part D Enrollees in 2022. ASPE Issue Brief No. HP-2024-03. March 7, 2024. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/reports/generic-drug-use-among-part-d-enrollees-2022
  48. US Department of Health and Human Services. A Report in Response to the Executive Order on Lowering Prescription Drug Costs for Americans. 2023. Feb 14. Available at: https://www.cms.gov/priorities/innovation/data-and-reports/2023/eo-rx-drug-cost-response-report
  49. S. Senate Special Committee on Aging. Sudden Price Spikes in Off-Patent Prescription Drugs: The Monopoly Business Model that Harms Patients, Taxpayers, and the U.S. Health Care System. U.S. Government Printing Office. December 2016; Special Report. Available at: www.aging.senate.gov
  50. https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/presidential-actions/2021/07/09/executive-order-on-promoting-competition-in-the-american-economy/
  51. Wiggins, S., and R. Maness. Price Competition in Pharmaceuticals: The Case of Anti-infectives. Economic Inquiry. 2004; 42: 247–263. Available at: http://www.fgcasal.org/politicafarmaceutica/docs/steven wiggins and robert maness.pdf
  52. Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE) RAND Report. 2024. Comparing Prescription Drugs in the U.S. and Other Countries: Prices and Availability. Jan 31, 2024. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/reports/comparing-prescription-drugs

FOOTNOTE

[1] See https://blogs.fda.gov/fdavoice/index.php/2018/02/2017-was-another-record-setting-year-for-generic-drugs/. FDA approved 843 full approvals and 184 tentative approvals in 2017 alone. For 2019, see https://blogs.fda.gov/fdavoice/index.php/2018/02/2017-was-another-record-setting-year-for-generic-drugs/

[2] On September 30, 2022, the President signed into law the FDA User Fee Reauthorization Act of 2022, which includes the reauthorization of the Generic Drug User Fee Amendments (GDUFA) through September 2027 (GDUFA III). Congress first enacted GDUFA in 2012 (GDUFA I), then re-authorized GDUFA II in 2017 which authorized the continued collection of user fees from generic-drug manufacturers to provide additional resources to the FDA for generic-drug reviews through fiscal year 2022 (https://www.fda.gov/industry/fda-user-fee-programs/generic-drug-user-fee-amendments).

[3] Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE) RAND Report. 2024. Comparing Prescription Drugs in the U.S. and Other Countries: Prices and Availability. Jan 31, 2024. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/reports/comparing-prescription-drugs

[4] US Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). Competition and Prices in Generic Drug Markets 20072018. ASPE Issue Brief No. HP-2021-01. January 19, 2021. Available at: https://aspe.hhs.gov/reports/medicare-part-d-competition-generic-drug-prices-2007-2018

[5] For this literature review focusing on the U.S. market, we exclude studies using pre-1984 data, the year the Waxman Hatch Act was passed that dramatically changed the landscape of the generic drug industry.

[6] The number of competitors, N, enters the model as a continuous variable.

[7] This semi-parametric or more flexible specification would be able to detect any non-linear relationship between the number of competitors and prices.

[8] The PDE contains drug ingredient costs, dispensing fees, and benefit design and payment data that enable CMS to make payments to the plans and otherwise administer the Part D benefit. It does not have prices net of rebates and discounts paid to payers. Brand prices may be overstated. For example, in 2014, the CMS Office of the Actuary estimates that rebates average 17.5% for brand drugs, varying widely across therapeutic classes (https://www.cms.gov/research-statistics-data-and-systems/statistics-trends-and-reports/information-on-prescription-drugs/partd_rebates)

[9] Biosimilars undergo a different approval process and have fundamentally different manufacturing processes so are expected to have very different generic pricing schemes relative to small-molecule drugs. During the time period of this study only 0-2 are in the market, so we excluded them.

[10] This is equivalent to a GPI-12 drug designation. The Generic Product Identifier (GPI) is a 14-character hierarchical classification system available in MediSpan that identifies drugs from their primary therapeutic use down to the unique interchangeable product regardless of manufacturer or package size. The GPI-12 summarizes the GPI-14 across strength (s.a. 10mg) and defines a drug product by a combination of therapeutic class, drug name, dosage form or route of administration (s.a. capsule).

[11] To construct the drug, we crosswalk the Medicare part D event data (PDE) at the NDC level to MediSpan at the GPI-14 level then summarize across strength to the GPI-12 level. Labelers at the NDC level are summarized to the GPI-12 level as well.

[12] Drugs are identified and reported using a unique, three-segment number called the National Drug Code (NDC) which serves as the FDA’s identifier for drugs. FDA publishes the listed NDC numbers in the NDC Directory which is updated daily. More information at: https://www.fda.gov/drugs/drug-approvals-and-databases/national-drug-code-directory

[13] For sensitivity analyses, we will also extend the baseline pre-generic brand price from 6 months to 2 years prior to first generic entry.

[14] We would argue that the number of competitors is exogenous in this study’s construct, hence, a single reduced form equation is adequate for two reasons. First, the current change in price shouldn’t affect the current change in the number of firms in the market since it takes several years of preparatory activities before a generic firm can enter the market. Therefore, if we exclude “late entrants”, which we are doing by limiting the time period to the 2 years or 3 years after 1st generic entry, we should not have a reverse causality problem between prices and number of firms producing the molecule-form.

[15] For sensitivity analyses, we also extend the baseline pre-generic brand price from 6 months to 2 years prior to first generic entry. The results do not differ significantly.

[16] Following the FDA, using the average brand price of the drug during 3 months prior to the first generic entry, we extend to 6 months to ensure exogeneity of the baseline price given that the brand drug manufacturer might vary its price in anticipation of imminent generic competition. (Ryan Conrad, Lutter R., 2019)

[17] A labeler is any firm that manufactures (including repackers or relabelers), or distributes (under its own name) the drug. In other words, a labeler identifies the manufacturer or distributor of the drug product (i.e., Pfizer, Allergan (Mylan), Watson, Teva, etc.).

[18] This analysis is presented at the “labeler” level, but results are robust at the “manufacturer” level as well. As a result of mergers and acquisition in these markets, a manufacturer may be responsible for multiple labeler codes. As there are more labelers than manufacturers, the estimated effect of competition when the number of competitors is based on labelers is likely to be conservative, at the least, not overstated.

[19] Using binary variables is often preferred because it does not assume a particular functional form (e.g., linear) for the relationship between the number of labelers and price.

[20] The drug-group is defined based on the GPI-2, Generic Product Identifier classification level 2. More information are available at: https://www.wolterskluwercdi.com/drug-data/gpi/

In addition, our 95% confidence intervals reported in Table 3 reflect the clustered standard errors (or Liang-Zeger standard errors) by assuming that the variance is non-constant between clusters, but constant within clusters.

[21] This split in 2012 is important given the finding that generic churning (entry and exit) generally increases until around 2012 then decreases or remains flat thereafter [Conti, Rena M.; Berndt, Ernst R. (2019)].

[22] The predicted relative prices are estimated by the difference of 1 and the sum of the marginal impacts on relative prices associated with each number of competitors reported in Table 3 and the estimated impact of the control group.

[23] An informal look at the confidence intervals in Table 3 suggests that these differences are not significant.

[24] Wiggins and Maness (2004), for instance, also found continuing price decline from a few sellers to more than 40 [50]

Article Statistics

Track views and downloads to measure the impact and reach of your article.

0

PDF Downloads

19 views

Metrics

PlumX

Altmetrics

Paper Submission Deadline

Track Your Paper

Enter the following details to get the information about your paper

GET OUR MONTHLY NEWSLETTER